전체기사 최신뉴스 GAM
KYD 디데이
글로벌

속보

더보기

윌리엄 풀 세인트루이스 연준총재, '거시지표' 주제 연설(원문)

기사입력 : 2006년10월17일 16:58

최종수정 : 2006년10월17일 16:58

※ 본문 글자 크기 조정

  • 더 작게
  • 작게
  • 보통
  • 크게
  • 더 크게

※ 번역할 언어 선택

Data, Data and Yet More Data
William Poole*
President, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The Association for University Business and Economic Research (AUBER) Annual Meeting
University of Memphis
Memphis, Tenn.
Oct. 16, 2006

*I appreciate comments provided by my colleagues at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Robert H. Rasche, senior vice president and director of research, provided special assistance. However, I take full responsibility for errors. The views expressed are mine and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Data, Data and Yet More Data

I am very pleased to be here today at the annual meeting of the Association for University Business and Economic Research. I’ve long had an interest in data, and I think that this topic is a good one for this conference. The topic is also one I’ve not addressed in a speech.

A personal recollection might be a good place to begin. In the early 1960s, in my Ph.D. studies at the University of Chicago, I was fortunate to be a member of Milton Friedman’s Money Workshop. Friedman stoked my interest in flexible exchange rates, in an era when mainstream thinking was focused on the advantages of fixed exchange rates and central banks everywhere were committed to maintaining the gold standard. Well, I should say central banks almost everywhere, given that Canada had a floating rate system from 1950 to 1962. Friedman got me interested in doing my Ph.D. dissertation on the Canadian experience with a floating exchange rate, and later I did a paper on nine other floating rate regimes in the 1920s. For this paper I collected daily data on exchange rates from musty paper records at the Board of Governors in Washington.

What was striking about the debates over floating rates in the 1950s is that economists were so willing to speculate about how currency speculators would destabilize foreign exchange markets without presenting any evidence to support those views. In this and many other areas, careful empirical research has resolved many disputes. Our profession has come a long way in institutionalizing empirical approaches to resolving empirical disputes. The enterprise requires data, and what I will discuss is some of the history of the role of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis in providing the data.

Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that the views I express here are mine and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis for their comments. Robert H. Rasche, senior vice president and director of research, provided special assistance. However, I retain full responsibility for errors.

Origins
The distribution of economic data by the Research department of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis can be traced back at least to May 1961. At that time, Homer Jones, then director of research, sent out a memo with three tables attached showing rates of change of the money supply (M1), money supply plus time deposits, and money supply plus time deposits plus short-term government securities. His memo indicated that he “would be glad to hear from anyone who thinks such time series have value, concerning promising applications or interpretations.” Recollections of department employees from that time were that the mailing list was about 100 addressees.

Apparently Homer received significant positive feedback, since various statistical releases emerged from this initial effort. Among these were Weekly Financial Data, subsequently U.S. Financial Data; Bank Reserves and Money, subsequently Monetary Trends; National Economic Trends (1967) and International Economic Trends (1978), all of which continue to this date. In April 1989, before a subscription price was imposed, the circulation of U.S. Financial Data had reached almost 45,000. A Business Week article published in 1967 commented about Homer that “while most leading monetary economists don’t buy his theories, they eagerly subscribe to his numbers.”(1) As an aside, as a Chicago Ph.D. I both bought the theories and subscribed to the data publications. By the late 1980s, according to Beryl Sprinkel, a prominent business economist of the time, “weekly and monthly publications of the Research Department, which have now become standard references for everyone from undergraduates to White House officials, were initially Homer’s products.”(2)

Why should a central bank distribute data as a public service? Legend has it that Homer Jones viewed as an important part of his mission to provide the general public with timely information about the stance of monetary policy. In this sense he was an early proponent, perhaps the earliest proponent, of central bank accountability and transparency. While Homer was a dedicated monetarist, and data on monetary aggregates have always figured prominently in St. Louis Fed data publications, data on other variables prominent in the monetary policy debates at the time, including short-term interest rates, excess reserves and borrowings, were included in the data releases.

Early on, the various St. Louis Fed data publications incorporated “growth triangles,” which tracked growth rates of monetary aggregates over varying horizons. Accompanying graphs of the aggregates included broken trend lines that illustrated rises and falls in growth rates. This information featured prominently in monetarist critiques of “stop-go” and procyclical characteristics of monetary policy during the Great Inflation period.

Does the tradition of data distribution initiated by Homer Jones remain a valuable public service? I certainly believe so. But I will also note that the St. Louis Fed’s data resources are widely used within the Federal Reserve System. This information is required for Fed research and policy analysis; the extra cost of making the information available also to the general public is modest.

Rational Expectations Macroeconomic Equilibrium
The case for making data readily available is simple. Most macroeconomists today adhere to a model based on the idea of a rational expectations equilibrium. Policymakers are assumed to have a set of goals, a conception of how the economy works and information about the current state and history of the economy. The private sector understands, to the extent possible, policymakers’ views, and has access to the same information about the state and history of the economy as policymakers have.

An equilibrium requires a situation in which the private sector has a clear understanding of policy goals and the policymakers’ model of the economy, and the policy model of the economy is as accurate as economic science permits. Based on this understanding, market behavior depends centrally on expectations concerning monetary policy and the effects of monetary policy on the economy, including effects on inflation, employment and financial stability. If the policymakers and private market participants do not have views that converge, no stable equilibrium is possible because expectations as to the behavior of others will be constantly changing.

The economy evolves in response to stochastic disturbances of all sorts. The continuous flow of new information includes everything that happens—weather disturbances, technological developments, routine economic data reports and the like. The core of my policy model is that market responses and policy responses to new information are both maximizing—households maximize utility, firms maximize profits and policymakers maximize their policy welfare function.

A critical assumption in this model is the symmetry of the information that is available to both policymakers and private market participants. In cases where the policymakers have an informational advantage over market participants, policy likely will not unfold in the way that markets expect, and the equilibrium that I have characterized here will not emerge. Hence public access to current information on the economy at low cost is a prerequisite to good policy outcomes.

The Evolution of St. Louis Fed Data Services
Data services provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis have evolved significantly from the paper publications initiated by Homer Jones. The initial phase of this evolution began in April 1991 when FRED, Federal Reserve Economic Data, was introduced as a dial-up electronic bulletin board. This service was not necessarily low cost. For users in the St. Louis area, access was available through a local phone call. For everyone else, long-distance phone charges were incurred. Nevertheless, within the first month of service, usage was recorded from places as wide ranging as Taipei, London, England and Vancouver, Canada.(3) FRED was relatively small scale. The initial implementation included only the data published in U.S. Financial Data and a few other time series. Subsequently it was expanded to include the data published in Monetary Trends, National Economic Trends and International Economic Trends. At the end of 1995, the print versions of these four statistical publications contained short histories on approximately 200 national and international variables; initially FRED was of comparable scope.

The next step occurred in 1996 when FRED migrated to the World Wide Web. At that point, 403 national time series became available instantaneously to anyone who had a personal computer with a Web browser. An additional 70 series for the Eighth Federal District were also available. The data series were in text format and had to be copied and pasted into the user’s PC. In July 2002, FRED became a true database and the user was offered a wider range of options. Data can be downloaded in either text or Excel format. Shortly thereafter user accounts were introduced so that multiple data series can be downloaded into a single Excel workbook, and data lists can be stored for repeated downloads of updated information. In the first six months after this version of FRED was released, 3.8 million hits were recorded to the website. In a recent six-month period, FRED received 21 million hits from over 109 countries around the world. FRED currently contains 1175 national time series and 1881 regional series. FRED data are updated on a real-time basis as information is released from various statistical agencies.

After 45 years, Homer Jones’s modest initiative to distribute data on three variables has developed into a broad-based data resource on the U.S. economy that is available at the click of a mouse around the globe. Through this resource, researchers, students, market participants and the general public can reach informed decisions based on information that is comparable to the information policymakers have.

In the past year we have introduced a number of additional data services. One of these, ALFRED, adds a vintage (or real-time) dimension to FRED. The ALFRED database stores revision histories of the FRED data series. Since 1996, we have maintained monthly or weekly archives of the FRED database. All the information in these archives has been populated to the ALFRED database, and the user can access point-in-time revisions of these data.(4) We have also extended the revision histories of many series back in time using data that were recorded in U.S. Financial Data, Monetary Trends and National Economic Trends. For selected quarterly National Income and Product data we have complete revision histories back to 1959 for real data and 1947 for nominal data. Revision histories are available on household and payroll employment data back to 1960. A similar history for industrial production is available back to 1927.

Preserving such information is crucial to understanding historical monetary policy. For example, Orphanides shows “that real-time policy recommendations differ considerably from those obtained with ex-post revised data. Further, estimated policy reaction functions based on ex-post revised data provide misleading descriptions of historical policy and obscure the behavior suggested by information available to the Federal Reserve in real time.”(5) Orphanides concludes that “reliance on the information actually available to policymakers in real time is essential for the analysis of monetary policy rules.”(6)

Such vintage information also is essential for analysis of conditions at subnational levels. For example, in January 2005 the BLS estimated that nonfarm employment in the St. Louis MSA had increased by 38.8 thousand between December 2003 and December 2004. This increase was widely cited as evidence that the MSA had returned to strong employment growth after four years of negative job growth. However, these data from the Current Employment Statistics (CES) were not benchmarked to more comprehensive labor market information that is available only with a lag.(7) The current estimate of nonfarm employment growth in the St. Louis MSA for this period, after several revisions, is only 11.6 thousand, less than 30 percent of the increase originally reported.

Another data initiative that we launched several years ago is FRASER – the Federal Reserve Archival System for Economic Research. The objective of this initiative is to digitize and distribute the monetary and economic record of the U.S. economy. FRASER is a repository of image files of important historical documents and serial publications. At present we have posted the entire history of The Economic Report of the President, Economic Indicators and Business Conditions Digest. We have also posted images of most issues of the Survey of Current Business from 1925 through 1990 and are working on filling in images of the remaining volumes. The collection also includes Banking and Monetary Statistics and the Annual Statistical Digests published by the Board of Governors, as well as the Business Statistics supplements to the Survey of Current Business published by the Department of Commerce. We are currently working, in a joint project with the Board of Governors, to image the entire history of the Federal Reserve Bulletin. Finally, we are posting images of historical statistical releases that we have collected in the process of extending the vintage histories in ALFRED back in time. These images should allow scholars, analysts and students of economic history to reconstruct vintage data on many series in addition to those we are maintaining on ALFRED.

Transparency, Accountability and Information Distribution
As just indicated, the scope of the archival information in FRASER extends beyond numeric data. Ready access to a wide variety of information is essential for transparency and accountability of monetary authorities and a full understanding of policy actions by the public. Since 1994 the Federal Reserve System and the FOMC have improved the scope and timeliness of information releases. I have discussed this progress in previous speeches.(8) Currently the FOMC releases a press statement at the conclusion of each scheduled meeting and three weeks later follows up with the release of minutes of the meeting. The press release and the minutes of the meetings record the vote on the policy action. The policy statement and minutes give the public a clear understanding of the action taken and insight into the rationale for the action.

Contrast the current situation with the one in 1979. At that time, actions by the Board of Governors on discount rate changes were reported promptly, but there was no press release subsequent to an FOMC policy action and FOMC meeting minutes were released with a 90-day delay. On Sept. 19, 1979, the Board of Governors voted by the narrow margin of 4-3 to approve a ½ percentage-point increase in the discount rate, with all three dissents against the increase. This information generated the public perception that the Fed officials were sharply divided and, therefore, that the Fed was not prepared to act decisively against inflation. John Berry, a knowledgeable reporter at the Washington Post, observed that “the split vote, with its clear signal that from the Fed’s own point of view interest rates are at or close to their peak for this business cycle, might forestall any more increases in market interest rates.”(9) However, the interpretation of the “clear signal” was erroneous. On that same day, the FOMC had voted 8 to 4 to raise the range for the intended funds rate to 11-1/4 to 11-3/4 percent. More importantly, three of the four dissents were in favor of a more forceful action to restrain inflation.(10) Neither the FOMC’s action, the dissents nor the rationale for the dissents were revealed to the public under the disclosure policies then in effect. The result was to destabilize markets, with commodity markets, in particular, exhibiting extreme volatility.

Conclusion
The tradition of data services was well established when I arrived in St. Louis in 1998, and I must say that I am proud that leadership in the Bank’s Research division has extended that tradition. Data are the lifeblood of empirical research in economics and of policy analysis. Our rational expectations conception of how the macroeconomy works requires that the markets and general public understand what the Fed is doing and why. Of all the things on which we spend money in the Federal Reserve, surely the return on our data services is among the highest.

 

References
1. “Maverick in the Fed System,” Business Week, November 18, 1967.

2. Beryl W. Sprinkel, “Confronting Monetary Policy Dilemmas: the Legacy of Homer Jones,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, March 1987, p 6.

3. “Introducing FRED,” Eighth Note, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, May/June 1991, p. 1.

4. We do not maintain histories of daily data series in ALFRED. Interest rates and exchange rates appear at daily frequencies in FRED. In principal these data are not revised, though occasional recording errors are observed to slip into the initial data releases. Such reporting errors get corrected in subsequent publications, so sometimes there is a vintage dimension to one of these series.

5. A. Orphanides, “Monetary Policy Rules Based on Real-Time Data,” American Economic Review, 91(4), September 2001, pp. 964.

6. ibid.

7. H.J. Wall and C.H. Wheeler, “St. Louis Employment in 2004: A Tale of Two Surveys,” CRE8 Occasional Report No. 2005-1, February 9, 2005.

8. See for example, FOMC Transparency,

9. J. Berry, “Fed Lists Discount Rate to Peak of 11% on Close Vote,” Washington Post, September 19, 1979, p. A1.

10. See, D.E. Lindsey, A. Orphanides, and R.H. Rasche, “The Reform of October 1979: How it Happened and Why,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Reivew, 87(2), Part 2,March/April 2005, pp 195-6.

[뉴스핌 베스트 기사]

사진
李정부, 123개 국정과제 공식 확정 [세종=뉴스핌] 양가희 기자 = 정부가 향후 5년간 국정 운영의 핵심 로드맵이 될 123대 국정과제를 본격 추진한다. 정부는 16일 정부세종청사에서 국무회의를 열고 국정과제를 포함한 국정과제 관리계획을 확정했다고 밝혔다. 국무회의에서 확정된 123대 국정과제는 지난달 13일 국정기획위원회에서 제안한 '이재명 정부 국정운영 5개년 계획(안)'을 정부 차원의 검토 및 조정·보완을 거쳐 확정한 것이다. 이재명 대통령이 16일 오전 취임 후 처음으로 정부세종청사에서 국무회의를 직접 주재하면서 국가균형발전에 대한 발언을 하고 있다. [사진=KTV] 최종 확정된 국정과제 체계는 '국민이 주인인 나라, 함께 행복한 대한민국'이라는 국가비전 아래 5대 국정목표, 23대 추진전략, 123대 과제로 구성됐다. 5대 국정목표는 ▲국민이 하나되는 정치 ▲세계를 이끄는 혁신경제 ▲모두가 잘사는 균형성장 ▲기본이 튼튼한 사회 ▲국익 중심의 외교안보다. 우선 정부는 국민주권 실현 및 대통령 책임 강화를 위한 개헌을 추진한다. 4년 연임제 및 결선투표제 도입, 감사원 국회 소속 이관, 대통령 거부권 제한, 국무총리 국회추천제 도입 등이 개헌안에 담길 전망이다. 권력기관 개혁을 통한 민주주의 확립, 독자 인공지능(AI) 생태계 및 AI고속도로 구축, 5극3특 중심 혁신·일자리 거점 조성, 경제협력개발기구(OECD) 수준 산재 감축 등의 내용도 국정과제에 담겼다. 또 이재명 정부 임기 내 전시작전통제권 전환을 완료하는 강군 육성 방안도 포함됐다. 행정수도 세종 완성과 2차 공공기관 이전도 차질없이 진행할 계획이다.  이재명 대통령이 16일 오전 취임 후 처음으로 정부세종청사에서 국가균형발전 관련 국무회의를 직접 주재하고 있다. [사진=KTV] 국정과제 이행을 위한 범정부 추진체계도 구축한다. 온라인 국정관리시스템과 오프라인 범부처 협의체를 운영, 국정과제 추진상황을 지속 관리한다. 입법성과 조기 창출을 위해 법제처에 국정입법상황실을 두고, 국정과제 입법 전주기를 밀착 관리한다. 국정과제 중 입법조치가 필요한 사항은 법률 751건, 하위법령 215건 등 총 966건으로 나타났다. 이 중 법률안 110건은 연내 국회 제출하고, 하위법령 66건 올해 제·개정한다는 계획이다. 국정과제 추진과정에서 국민과의 소통을 강화하고, 정책성과를 국민이 실질적으로 체감할 수 있도록 한다. 온라인 소통창구인 '국정과제 소통광장'을 마련, 국민이 제기한 의견을 정부가 신속히 답하는 쌍방향 소통채널을 만든다. 국민만족도 조사는 주기적으로 실시하고 민생 관련 중요 국정과제는 민관합동 현장점검을 실시한다. 국정과제 추진성과를 평가하기 위한 '정부업무평가 기본계획('25~'27)' 및 '2025년도 정부업무평가 시행계획 수정안'도 이날 국무회의에서 확정됐다. 올해는 미래 전략산업 육성 등 각 부처가 역점 추진하는 정책과제, 신산업 등 규제 합리화, AI 활용 일하는 방식 혁신, 디지털 소통·홍보 노력 강화 등을 중점 평가할 예정이다. 국민주권정부에 걸맞게 평가 과정에 국민 참여를 확대하고, 국민 만족도 조사 결과도 비중 있게 반영한다. 국무조정실은 "향후 국정과제 추진과정에서 국민의견을 수시로 청취하고 소통을 강화해 나갈 예정"이라며 "국민요구와 정책여건 변화를 반영해 이행계획도 지속 보완하며 추진할 계획"이라고 밝혔다. sheep@newspim.com 2025-09-16 14:04
사진
코어위브, 엔비디아와 8조원대 계약 [서울=뉴스핌]박공식 기자 = 데이터센터 운영업체인 코어위브(종목코드: CRWV)는 인공지능(AI) 칩 선두 주자 엔비디아와 63억 달러(8조7160억원) 규모의 클라우드 컴퓨팅 용량 주문 계약을 체결했다고 15일(현지시간) 밝혔다. 엔비디아는 이번 계약을 통해 2032년 4월 13일 까지 코어위브가 고객에게 판매하지 않은 모든 클라우드 용량을 구매하기로 했다. 엔비디아와 수주 계약 체결 소식이 전해진 후 코어위브 주가는 뉴욕 정규장 거래에서 8% 상승했다. 지난 3월 상장 이후 이 회사 주가는 3배 뛰었다. 코어위브는 미국과 유럽에서 엔비디아의 GPU 칩을 탑재한 대규모 데이터센터를 운영하며 이를 임대하거나 클라우드 컴퓨팅 용량을 판매하고 있다. 이번 계약으로 코어위브는 엔비디아의 핵심 클라우드 파트너로서의 입지를 공고히 하고 AI 컴퓨팅 용량 수요 감소 가능성에 대한 완충장치를 마련하게 됐다고 로이터 통신은 평가했다. 코어위브는 일찌감치 엔비디아의 눈도장을 받아 2023년 투자를 받았다. 엔비디아는 코어위브 지분을 6% 넘게 보유하고 있다. 코어위브는 지난 3월 공모가 40달러에 뉴욕 증시에 상장한 후 AI 열풍에 따른 클라우드 서비스 수요 급증에 힘입어 주가가 급등했다. 투자은행 바클레이즈는 "이번 계약은 최종 고객과 상관없이 용량이 활용될 것을 보장함으로써 코어위브의 안전장치 역할을 한다"며 "투자자들은 코어위브가 최대 고객사 2곳(마이크로소프트와 오픈AI) 외에 데이터센터 용량을 채울 수 있을지 우려해왔는데, 이번 계약으로 이런 우려가 사라졌다"고 분석했다.  코어위브 로고 [서울=뉴스핌]박공식 기자 = 2025.09.16 kongsikpark@newspim.com 코어위브는 지난 3월 챗GPT 개발사 오픈AI와 119억 달러 규모의 5년 계약에 합의하며, 클라우드 컴퓨팅 용량을 제공하기로 한 바 있다. 오픈AI는 2029년 4월까지 40억 달러까지 지급하기로 약속하는 추가 협정을 맺었다. kongsikpark@newspim.com 2025-09-16 13:03
기사 번역
결과물 출력을 준비하고 있어요.
기사제목
기사가 번역된 내용입니다.
종목 추적기

S&P 500 기업 중 기사 내용이 영향을 줄 종목 추적

결과물 출력을 준비하고 있어요.

긍정 영향 종목

  • Lockheed Martin Corp. Industrials
    우크라이나 안보 지원 강화 기대감으로 방산 수요 증가 직접적. 미·러 긴장 완화 불확실성 속에서도 방위산업 매출 안정성 강화 예상됨.

부정 영향 종목

  • Caterpillar Inc. Industrials
    우크라이나 전쟁 장기화 시 건설 및 중장비 수요 불확실성 직접적. 글로벌 인프라 투자 지연으로 매출 성장 둔화 가능성 있음.
이 내용에 포함된 데이터와 의견은 뉴스핌 AI가 분석한 결과입니다. 정보 제공 목적으로만 작성되었으며, 특정 종목 매매를 권유하지 않습니다. 투자 판단 및 결과에 대한 책임은 투자자 본인에게 있습니다. 주식 투자는 원금 손실 가능성이 있으므로, 투자 전 충분한 조사와 전문가 상담을 권장합니다.
안다쇼핑
Top으로 이동